DOKK Library

Blockchains as infrastructure and semicommons

Authors James Grimmelmann

License CC-BY-4.0

Plaintext
BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS


                           JAMES GRIMMELMANN*

                             A. JASON WINDAWI**


                                     ABSTRACT

   Blockchains are not self-executing machines. They are resource
systems designed by people, maintained by people, and governed by
people. Their technical protocols help to solve some difficult problems
in shared resource management, but behind those protocols there are
always communities of people struggling with familiar challenges in
governing their provision and use of common infrastructure.
   In this Article, we describe blockchains as shared, distributed
transactional ledgers using two frameworks from commons theory.
Brett Frischmann’s theory of infrastructure provides an external
view, showing how blockchains provide useful, generic infrastructure
for recording transactions and why that infrastructure is most natu-
rally made available on common, nondiscriminatory terms. Henry
Smith’s theory of semicommons provides an internal view, showing
how blockchains intricately combine private resources (such as phys-
ical hardware and on-chain assets) with common resources (such as
the shared transactional ledger and the blockchain protocol itself).
We then detail how blockchains struggle with many of the gover-
nance challenges that these frameworks predict, requiring blockchain
communities to engage in extensive off-chain governance work to co-
ordinate their uses and achieve consensus. Blockchains function as


     * Tessler Family Professor of Digital and Information Law, Cornell Tech and Cornell
Law School. Our thanks to Aislinn Black, Tyler Kell, and Yan Ji. This essay may be freely
reused under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International license,
https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0.
    ** Ph.D., Sociology, Princeton University.


                                         1097
1098              WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW         [Vol. 64:1097

infrastructure and semicommons not in spite of the human element,
but because of it.
2023]    BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                                       1099


                                  TABLE OF CONTENTS

INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .       1100
I. INFRASTRUCTURE . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .        1104
   A. Definition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .   1104
   B. Ledgers as Infrastructure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .              1107
   C. Blockchains as Infrastructure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                1109
   D. Decentralization. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .        1110
II. SEMICOMMONS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .        1112
   A. Definition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .   1112
   B. Blockchains as Semicommons. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                    1116
III. GOVERNANCE . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .        1118
   A. Protocols and Software . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .             1119
   B. Turtles All the Way Up . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .             1121
   C. Resource Consumption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .               1122
   D. Tyranny of the Majority . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .              1124
   E. Consensus Breakdown. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .               1126
   F. Inherent Instability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .         1127
CONCLUSION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .     1129
1100                      WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                       [Vol. 64:1097


                                    INTRODUCTION

   Blockchains are black boxes—at least as far as legal scholarship
is concerned. Large and growing bodies of literature discuss the
potential applications of blockchains in fields including antitrust,1
contracts,2 commercial law,3 corporate law,4 financial regulation,5
property,6 securities law,7 and more.8 This scholarship largely takes
blockchains themselves as given and instead asks whether and how
law should regulate the various uses people make of blockchains.
   When legal scholarship does discuss the inner workings of a
blockchain, the details are treated primarily as a technical question.
The computer science of consensus protocols, cryptographic signa-
tures, mining, and transactions are described in enough detail to
explain how the underlying technology works and then set to one
side. This is the ambit of computer science, not of law. On this view,

     1. See, e.g., THIBAULT SCHREPEL, BLOCKCHAIN + ANTITRUST: THE DECENTRALIZATION
FORMULA (2021) (ebook).
     2. See, e.g., Kevin Werbach & Nicolas Cornell, Contracts Ex Machina, 67 DUKE L.J. 313,
322 (2017).
     3. See, e.g., Heather Hughes, Blockchain and the Future of Secured Transactions Law,
3 STAN. J. BLOCKCHAIN L. & POL’Y 21, 22-23 (2020); Carla L. Reyes, Creating Cryptolaw for the
Uniform Commercial Code, 78 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 1521 (2021); Kevin V. Tu, Perfecting
Bitcoin, 52 GA. L. REV. 505, 545-46, 555 (2018); Jeanne L. Schroeder, Bitcoin and the Uniform
Commercial Code, 24 U. MIA. BUS. L. REV. 1 (2016).
     4. See, e.g., Usha R. Rodrigues, Law and the Blockchain, 104 IOWA L. REV. 679 (2019);
Alexandra Andhov, Corporations on Blockchain: Opportunities & Challenges, 53 CORNELL
INT’L L.J. 1 (2020); Carla L. Reyes, If Rockefeller Were a Coder, 87 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 373
(2019); Kevin V. Tu, Blockchain Stock Ledgers, 96 IND. L.J. 223 (2020); George S. Geis,
Traceable Shares and Corporate Law, 113 NW. U. L. REV. 227 (2018).
     5. See, e.g., Hilary J. Allen, DeFi: Shadow Banking 2.0?, 64 WM. & MARY L. REV. 919
(2023).
     6. See, e.g., Juliet M. Moringiello & Christopher K. Odinet, The Property Law of Tokens,
74 FLA. L. REV. 607 (2022); Joshua A.T. Fairfield, Tokenized: The Law of Non-Fungible Tokens
and Unique Digital Property, 97 IND. L.J. 1261 (2022); Eric D. Chason, How Bitcoin Functions
as Property Law, 49 SETON HALL L. REV. 129 (2018).
     7. See, e.g., Yuliya Guseva, A Conceptual Framework for Digital-Asset Securities: Tokens
and Coins as Debt and Equity, 80 MD. L. REV. 166 (2021); Jonathan Rohr & Aaron Wright,
Blockchain-Based Token Sales, Initial Coin Offerings, and the Democratization of Public
Capital Markets, 70 HASTINGS L.J. 463 (2019).
     8. See, e.g., Bridget J. Crawford, Blockchain Wills, 95 IND. L.J. 735 (2020) (trusts and
estates). For general analyses of the relationship of blockchains to law, see KEVIN WERBACH,
THE BLOCKCHAIN AND THE NEW ARCHITECTURE OF TRUST (2018); AARON WRIGHT & PRIMAVERA
DE FILIPPI, BLOCKCHAIN AND THE LAW: THE RULE OF CODE (2018).
2023]    BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                              1101

legal scholars should care about what blockchains enable rather
than how they work.
   We disagree. We believe that legal theory should pay close
attention to the technical details of blockchains for two reasons.
   First, what is inside the black boxes is interesting in its own
right. Legal scholarship can illuminate how blockchains work. A
blockchain is, at heart, a set of rules for how to use a shared
resource, and this kind of coordination problem is a familiar subject
for property theory and intellectual property theory. Similar to
wikis and open-source software projects, blockchains are an impor-
tant real-world example of collaboration in action.9
   Second, black boxes do not always work. Legal scholarship can
explain how blockchains break. Predicting blockchains’ likely failure
modes is a central question for regulating them. The same tools
from legal theory that help explain when collaborations succeed can
also help explain when they fail. The history of blockchain
disasters—from the DAO hack to stolen apes—is most usefully ex-
plained in terms of their inner workings.10
   In this Article, we give a careful description of blockchains as
infrastructural semicommons.11 Our description draws on two
established lines of scholarship. First, we use Brett Frischmann’s
theory of infrastructure12 to position blockchains in larger streams

     9. See generally YOCHAI BENKLER, THE WEALTH OF NETWORKS: HOW SOCIAL PRODUCTION
TRANSFORMS MARKETS AND FREEDOM (2006).
    10. Some legal scholarship examines blockchain failure modes to extract lessons for
regulation. See, e.g., Shaanan Cohney, David Hoffman, Jeremy Sklaroff & David Wishnick,
Coin-Operated Capitalism, 119 COLUM. L. REV. 591 (2019) (analyzing technical flaws in smart
contracts); James Grimmelmann, All Smart Contracts Are Ambiguous, 2 J.L. & INNOVATION
1 (2019) (examining forks and other consensus breakdowns).
    11. We presume familiarity with the technical fundamentals of blockchains. For
references, see generally ARVIND NARAYANAN, JOSEPH BONNEAU, EDWARD FELTEN, ANDREW
MILLER & STEVEN GOLDFEDER, BITCOIN AND CRYPTOCURRENCY TECHNOLOGIES: A
COMPREHENSIVE INTRODUCTION (2016); ANDREAS M. ANTONOPOULOS & GAVIN WOOD,
MASTERING ETHEREUM: BUILDING SMART CONTRACTS AND DAPPS (2019). For a gentle
introduction, see generally Kevin Roose, The Latecomer’s Guide to Crypto, N.Y. TIMES (Mar.
18, 2022), https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2022/03/18/technology/cryptocurrency-crypto-
guide.html [https://perma.cc/RZ4Y-YEAZ]. For a critique, see Molly White, Matt Binder,
Grady Booch, Amy Castor, Stephen Diehl, Dirty Bubble Media, Catherine Flick, David
Gerard, Geoffrey Huntley, Bennett Tomlin, Neil Turkewitz & Ed Zitron, The (Edited)
Latecomer’s Guide to Crypto, MOLLYWHITE.NET (Mar. 25, 2022), https://www.mollywhite.net/
annotations/latecomers-guide-to-crypto [https://perma.cc/WGU7-SCGP].
    12. BRETT M. FRISCHMANN, INFRASTRUCTURE: THE SOCIAL VALUE OF SHARED RESOURCES,
1102                      WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                       [Vol. 64:1097

of production.13 On the one hand, blockchains are useful to their
users because they provide an infrastructural service: users can
record transactions and run sophisticated applications without
needing to trust a single centralized service operator.14 On the other
hand, blockchains themselves depend on a set of underlying infra-
structural resources.15 Some of this infrastructure (for example,
worldwide internet connectivity) is preexisting, but some of it (for
example, protocols and software) must be specifically provisioned for
a blockchain to function.16
   This infrastructural framework foregrounds the functional roles
that blockchain systems play but tells us relatively little about how
they are constructed. We fill in these details using Henry Smith’s
semicommons theory, which highlights the complex balance of
private (for example, individual computers, cryptocurrency tokens)
and commons property (for example, the blockchain protocol, the
history of blocks) that make the construction and ongoing function-
ing of a blockchain possible.17 Semicommons theory directs attention
to the boundaries between different resources, the mixed incentives
of different participants, and governance institutions.18
   The two frameworks are complementary. The infrastructure story
is demand-side. It explains blockchains from the outside in: why
they provide useful outputs and what inputs they require to func-
tion. The semicommons story is supply-side. It explains blockchains
from the inside out: how they are structured to overcome coordina-
tion and cooperation problems.

at xiii (2012); see also Yochai Benkler, Commons and Growth: The Essential Role of Open
Commons in Market Economies, 80 U. CHI. L. REV. 1499 (2013) (reviewing BRETT M.
FRISCHMANN, INFRASTRUCTURE: THE SOCIAL VALUE OF SHARED RESOURCES (2012)) (situating
Frischmann’s theory of infrastructure within commons theory more broadly).
    13. See Brett M. Frischmann, An Economic Theory of Infrastructure and Commons
Management, 89 MINN. L. REV. 917, 918-19 (2005); FRISCHMANN, supra note 12; GOVERNING
KNOWLEDGE COMMONS (Brett M. Frischmann et al. eds., 2014); Michael J. Madison, Brett M.
Frischmann & Katherine J. Strandburg, Constructing Commons in the Cultural Environment,
95 CORNELL L. REV. 657 (2010).
    14. See Frischmann, supra note 13, at 956 (explaining what constitutes an infrastructural
service).
    15. See id. at 928 (discussing examples of infrastructural resources).
    16. See id. at 1005-07.
    17. See Henry E. Smith, Exclusion Versus Governance: Two Strategies for Delineating
Property Rights, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S453, S453-54 (2002).
    18. See id. at S457.
2023]    BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                              1103

  Our analysis highlights the roles of different and overlapping
governance institutions in blockchains.19 Governance has long been
recognized as a key feature of commons management.20 An essential
task in mapping a commons resource is describing how its gover-
nance institutions are constituted and the rules they develop and
enforce.21 Although the commons form is sometimes treated as the
opposite of private property, recognizing commons governance and
private exclusion as two strategies for resource management is more
helpful.22 Infrastructural blockchain semicommons use both gover-
nance and exclusion in complementary ways.23 In particular, this
perspective emphasizes that socially based “off-chain” governance
plays an essential role in making technically based “on-chain”
exclusion work at all.24
  Part I of this Article gives a description of a blockchain as layered
infrastructure. It describes the essential features of a transactional
ledger and shows how Frischmann’s theory of infrastructure ele-
gantly captures these characteristics. Then, Part II shows how
blockchains overcome the coordination and cooperation problems
inherent in making a ledger distributed. Here, Smith’s theory of
semicommons succinctly describes the relevant moving parts. Next,
Part III complicates the story by demonstrating that blockchains
display precisely the tensions and instabilities that semicommons
theory predicts. These challenges are serious, and whether a
blockchain fails or succeeds often turns on whether its governance
institutions are capable of rising to the occasion. Finally, a brief

    19. We are not the first to consider blockchain governance. The most comprehensive the-
oretical framework is Enrico Rossi & Carsten Sørensen, Towards A Theory of Digital Network
De/Centralization: Platform-Infrastructure Lessons Drawn from Blockchain (Dec. 13, 2019)
(unpublished manuscript), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id= 3503609
[https://perma.cc/C66S-SPC4]. See also Rowan van Pelt, Slinger Jansen, Djuri Baars & Sietse
Overbeek, Defining Blockchain Governance: A Framework for Analysis and Comparison, 38
INFO. SYS. MGMT. 21, 21-22 (2021). See generally Yue Liu, Qinghua Lu, Liming Zhu, Hye-
Young Paik & Mark Staples, A Systematic Literature Review on Blockchain Governance
(Mar. 29, 2022) (unpublished manuscript), https://arxiv.org/abs/2105.054603 [https://
perma.cc/2HY3-MG4T].
    20. See ELINOR OSTROM, GOVERNING THE COMMONS: THE EVOLUTION OF INSTITUTIONS FOR
COLLECTIVE ACTION 1-2 (1990).
    21. See, e.g., Rossi & Sørensen, supra note 19, at 18.
    22. See Smith, supra note 17, at S454-55.
    23. See id.
    24. See, e.g., van Pelt et al., supra note 19, at 22, 30.
1104                       WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                        [Vol. 64:1097

conclusion reflects on the rhetoric of trust and community around
blockchains—seeing them as infrastructural semicommons helps
one understand what is really at stake in these conversations.

                                 I. INFRASTRUCTURE

A. Definition

  In Frischmann’s definition, a resource is infrastructure when it
has three characteristics.25 First, the resource is nonrival: it “may be
consumed nonrivalrously for some appreciable range of demand.”26
Nonrivalrousness means that the resource is capable of serving
multiple simultaneous uses.27 Second, the resource is valuable as an
input: demand for the resource “is driven primarily by downstream
productive activities that require the resource as an input.”28 Input
resources are valuable for what they enable rather than for direct
consumption.29 And third, the resource is generic: it “may be used as
an input into a wide range of goods and services, which may include


    25. FRISCHMANN, supra note 12, at 61. A related but less precisely theorized concept is the
“platform.” See, e.g., VITALIK BUTERIN, A NEXT-GENERATION SMART CONTRACT & DECENTRAL-
IZED APPLICATION PLATFORM 13 (2014), https://blockchainlab.com/pdf/Ethereum_white_paper-
a_next_generation_smart_contract_and_decentralized_application_platform-vitalik-buterin.
pdf [https://perma.cc/M5XE-6WJJ] (describing Ethereum as a platform). A definition from
economics is that a (multisided) platform enables direct interactions between two or more
distinct groups of users, each of which is affiliated with the platform. See Andrei Hagiu &
Julian Wright, Multi-Sided Platforms, 43 INT’L J. INDUS. ORG. 162, 163 (2015). A technical
definition is that a (computing) platform is standardized hardware, software, or service that
provides functionality developers can write software to make use of. (Other definitions em-
phasize the presence of network effects. See Juan Manuel Sanchez-Cartas & Gonzalo León,
Multisided Platforms and Markets: A Survey of the Theoretical Literature, 35 J. ECON. SURVS.
452, 453-57 (2021) (discussing competing definitions)). Combining these two definitions
recovers something that can function as a form of infrastructure in Frischmann’s sense. See
Ben Thompson, A Framework for Regulating Competition on the Internet, STRATECHERY (Dec.
9, 2019), https://stratechery.com/ 2019/a-framework-for-regulating-competition-on-the-inter
net/ [https://perma.cc/M2LV-JSCJ]. See generally Tarleton Gillespie, The Politics of ‘Plat-
forms,’ 12 NEW MEDIA & SOC’Y 347 (2010) (discussing ambiguities of “platform” terminology);
Rossi & Sørensen, supra note 19, at 8-10 (discussing platform/infrastructure distinction and
reviewing literature).
    26. FRISCHMANN, supra note 12, at 61.
    27. See id. at 62.
    28. Id. at 61.
    29. See id. at 61, 63.
2023]   BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                             1105

private goods, public goods, and social goods.”30 Genericity means
that analysis of the resource cannot be assimilated to the analysis
of its sole productive use.31 Classic examples of infrastructure
include roads and other transportation networks, telecommunica-
tions networks, the natural environment, ideas, and languages.32
   But Frischmann also points to a pervasive dilemma of infrastruc-
ture. Many of the downstream uses that infrastructure supports
create positive spillovers that have social benefit exceeding their
private value to the user.33 Many of these spillovers go beyond the
consumer surplus that attaches to any good in a world without
perfect price discrimination.34 Some uses have network effects. For
example, each additional user of a currency standard reduces the
average information costs of pricing in a way that benefits all
existing users. Other uses are true public goods that benefit every-
one, whether or not they also use the infrastructure.35 New ideas are
public goods in this sense.36
   The problem is that the infrastructure users who create positive
spillovers cannot and will not pay for all of the value they confer on
society.37 This means that the traditional property strategy of treat-
ing a resource as a private good, with a price based on a user’s
willingness to pay, fails for infrastructure.38 Users will pay for the
private value they individually realize from using the infrastruc-
ture, but that is less than the full social value their use creates.39
The private owner of the infrastructure will price access above the
point that would be efficient for society overall, resulting in under-
use.40 Some of the uses that the infrastructure could support (be-
cause it is nonrival) will be lost because the private infrastructure



    30. Id. at 61.
    31. See id. at 64-65.
    32. Id. at 3-4.
    33. Id. at 63-64; Brett M. Frischmann & Mark A. Lemley, Essay, Spillovers, 107 COLUM.
L. REV. 257, 257 (2007).
    34. See Frischmann & Lemley, supra note 33, at 262.
    35. See id. at 259.
    36. See id. at 259 n.4.
    37. See id. at 271-74.
    38. See id. at 258.
    39. See id.
    40. See FRISCHMANN, supra note 12, at 66.
1106                    WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                    [Vol. 64:1097

owner has too weak an incentive to allow them (because of unin-
ternalized spillovers).41
   Frischmann’s solution to this dilemma is commons management,
“in which a resource is shared among members of a community on
nondiscriminatory terms ... that do not depend on the users’ identity
or intended use.”42 Anyone within the relevant community who
wants to use the infrastructure can, and they can do so on substan-
tially the same terms as anyone else.43 Treating infrastructure as a
commons encourages wider use, including publicly valuable uses
that cannot pay their own way.44 Frischmann traces the commons-
management strategy in numerous infrastructural resources,
including communications networks and knowledge resources.45
   Commons governance of infrastructure faces two characteristic
challenges. On the demand side, it must prevent congestion due to
overuse.46 While pure public goods, such as ideas, are inexhaustible,
other kinds of infrastructure, such as roads and telephone networks,
have limited capacity.47 When that capacity is reached or exceeded,
their quality degrades and users suffer.48 So some kind of mecha-
nism should deter use beyond the point at which the use’s marginal
value is exceeded by the negative spillovers it causes for other users.
On the supply side, governance must create sufficient incentives to
provision the resource in the first place.49 For ideas, this is the
intellectual property problem of incentives for creation.50 For
tangible infrastructure such as roads and communications net-
works, someone must physically create and maintain the infrastruc-
ture. So somehow compensation should flow to those who do the
work of creation and maintenance.

   41. See Frischmann & Lemley, supra note 33, at 265-66.
   42. FRISCHMANN, supra note 12, at 92.
   43. See id. at 91-114; Frischmann, supra note 13, at 926; GOVERNING KNOWLEDGE
COMMONS, supra note 13, at 29-30. See generally James Grimmelmann, The Virtues of
Moderation, 17 YALE J.L. & TECH. 42 (2015) (giving taxonomy of management strategies in
the context of content moderation).
   44. See Frischmann, supra note 13, at 975-78.
   45. See FRISCHMANN, supra note 12, at 61.
   46. See James Grimmelmann, The Internet Is a Semicommons, 78 FORDHAM L. REV. 2799,
2806-10 (2010) (discussing overuse challenges).
   47. See id. at 2806, 2810-12.
   48. See id. at 2806-10.
   49. See id. at 2810-12 (discussing provisioning challenges).
   50. Frischmann & Lemley, supra note 33, at 266.
2023]    BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                              1107

   There are two traditional solutions to these challenges. One is
direct public provisioning, in which the government pays for the
infrastructure out of general tax revenues.51 This is how roads work,
for example, and as a result, they are typically free to users.52 The
other is public utility regulation, in which the infrastructure is
privately provided, but the government regulates the terms on and
prices at which it is provided to users to ensure nondiscriminatory
access at a price that maximizes overall social value.53

B. Ledgers as Infrastructure

   Transactional ledgers are infrastructure under Frischmann’s
definition. Consider a county land title office for recording deeds and
other documents. First, up to the capacity of the ledger, its use is
nonrival. One person filing a deed does not interfere with anyone
else’s ability to file one.54 Second, the ledger is useful as an input.
Other than historians and property scholars, few people enjoy
browsing through land title records for its own sake. Rather, the
records are useful for facilitating secure land transactions. And
third, the ledger is generic. It helps support all uses of land. The
ledger is an input into home purchases, into factory construction,
into secured lending, into environmental studies, and more.
   It is important to distinguish between four related resources in a
ledger, which can be illustrated using the traditional land title
office. First, there is the physical hardware on which the ledger
operates: the paper files or digital computers that tangibly and
persistently store property records. These are private resources—
one cannot just walk into a land title office and walk out with the
file cabinets. Second, there is the ledger itself: the recording service
the office provides. This is the infrastructural resource itself, and it
is managed as a commons.55 Third, there is the information on the
ledger: the details of who owns what, who sent what to whom, and
what computations have taken place. This information is a pure

   51. See FRISCHMANN, supra note 12, at 196.
   52. See id.
   53. See id. at 108-14.
   54. See Frischmann, supra note 13, at 942 (describing nonrivalry as a situation in which
one individual’s consumption does not hinder consumption opportunities for others).
   55. See FRISCHMANN, supra note 12, at 92-93.
1108                      WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                       [Vol. 64:1097

public good: it is nonrival and nonexcludable.56 And fourth, there are
the assets tracked on the ledger: legal interests in land, easements,
and mortgages. These assets are private goods.57 To summarize,
private hardware is used to construct a common ledger that records
common information about private assets.
   The relationship between these resources can be usefully
described in terms of modularity and layering. A modular system is
one in which individual components can be divided into distinct
modules—“specialized units that operate semi-autonomously from
other specialized units.”58 Each module is tightly coupled internally,
but loosely coupled to other modules.59 In a modular system, a
module serving a particular function can be swapped out for one
performing the same or a similar function without significantly
affecting the other modules in the system.60 Replacing one computer
with another in the recording office is invisible to users; they will
not notice that the office has migrated its database from Oracle to
MySQL.
   Layering is a specific, and highly fruitful, type of modularity.61 In
a layered system, components are divided into distinct layers based
on their functions, interactions, and dependencies.62 In its ideal-
typical form, each layer interacts only with the layers immediately
above and beneath it and depends only on the layer immediately
beneath it.63 For example, the internet is commonly divided into a
physical layer (hardware), a link layer (protocols designed for


    56. See id. at 62.
    57. See id. at 24-25.
    58. Thomas W. Merrill, Response, Property as Modularity, 125 HARV. L. REV. F. 151, 155
(2012); see also Henry E. Smith, Property as the Law of Things, 125 HARV. L. REV. 1691, 1700-
01 (2012) (presenting a modular theory of property); Henry E. Smith, Modularity in Contracts:
Boilerplate and Information Flow, 104 MICH. L. REV. 1175, 1180-81 (2006) (applying
modularity to boilerplate contracts).
    59. See Merrill, supra note 58, at 155.
    60. See id.
    61. See generally Lawrence B. Solum & Minn Chung, The Layers Principle: Internet
Architecture and the Law, 79 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 815 (2004) (describing the internet as a
layered system); JONATHAN ZITTRAIN, THE FUTURE OF THE INTERNET—AND HOW TO STOP IT
(2008) (analyzing layering within networks); BARBARA VAN SCHEWICK, INTERNET ARCHITEC-
TURE AND INNOVATION (2010) (explaining layering in internet architecture).
    62. See generally VAN SCHEWICK, supra note 61, for a description of the internet as a
layered system.
    63. See id. at 47.
2023]    BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                                1109

specific kinds of hardware), a network layer (internet protocol,
which is universal across the internet, and from whence the “IP” in
“IP address” derives), a transport layer (for example, protocols such
as HTTP that are optimized for classes of applications), and an
application layer (for example, Skype, Netflix, or Facebook).64 In the
ideal form, applications do not deal directly with the physical, link,
or hardware layers; instead, they make requests of and receive
information back from the transport layer.65 Facebook does not
know and does not care whether it is running on a DOCSIS-based
cable network or a 4G-based wireless network.66
   From a layers perspective, the recording office resource system
has three layers. There is a physical-hardware layer, which supports
a ledger-service layer, which records information about a property-
interests layer. The hardware is private, the ledger service is
managed as a commons, and the property interests are private.

C. Blockchains as Infrastructure

   Blockchains are ledgers, and as such they are infrastructure.67
One of the reasons for the widespread interest in blockchains is that
they can be particularly generic as ledgers. Blockchains support
cryptocurrencies such as Bitcoin and Ether.68 Blockchains support
asset-ownership tokens, such as Bored Apes, corporate shares, and
titanium cubes.69 And blockchains support smart-contract-based
applications: games such as Axie Infinity,70 investment schemes




    64. See Solum & Chung, supra note 61, at 839-40.
    65. See id. at 840.
    66. Cf. BUTERIN, supra note 25, at 13 (describing Ethereum as “essentially the ultimate
abstract foundational layer”).
    67. See, e.g., Chason, supra note 6, at 135-37, 147, 156 (comparing traditional recording
system and blockchain); Benito Arruñada, Blockchain’s Struggle to Deliver Impersonal
Exchange, 19 MINN. J.L. SCI. & TECH. 55, 58-60 (2018).
    68. See Arruñada, supra note 67, at 58.
    69. See id. at 61.
    70. See Joshua Brustein, A Billion-Dollar Crypto Gaming Startup Promised Riches and
Delivered Disaster, BLOOMBERG (June 10, 2022, 5:00 AM), https://www.bloomberg.com/
news/features/2022-06-10/axie-infinity-axs-crypto-game-promised-nft-riches-gave-ruin
[https://perma.cc/6LGU-NU6C].
1110                     WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                      [Vol. 64:1097

such as SpiceDAO,71 and economic exchanges such as prediction
markets.72
   A (public) blockchain is also a commons in Frischmann’s sense.73
It has no restrictions on who can record transactions in its ledger or
who can read them.74 While some blockchains have transaction fees,
such as paying for gas on Ethereum, those fees are nondiscrimina-
tory.75 The pricing is based entirely on the intensity of one’s use (for
example, how much work the Ethereum Virtual Machine must do
for one’s transaction) rather than on the identity of the user or on
how much value they are extracting from the use.76
   One of the salient points about blockchains—which puts the
“crypto” in “cryptocurrency”—is that the ledger entries are secured
with digital signatures. Only a user who knows the private key to
the address associated with a blockchain asset can create a
transaction that uses or transfers that asset.77 As long as users are
able to keep their private keys secret, this makes these assets both
rival and excludable: true private goods.78 Thus, a blockchain can be
used not just to record information about property rights in already-
existing, off-chain assets but to create and enforce property rights
in new on-chain assets.

D. Decentralization

  Public provision of ledgers can be an attractive strategy because
a ledger database is not especially costly. Publicly provisioned
ledgers include land records and ownership of intellectual property

    71. See Adi Robertson, They Spent $3 Million on a Dune Script Bible—Now What?, THE
VERGE (Feb. 28, 2022, 9:07 AM), https://www.theverge.com/2022/2/28/22950868/spice-dao-
crypto-jodorowsky-dune-bible-collective-writing-contest [https://perma.cc/JY2V-UEDG].
    72. Clay Graubard & Andrew Eaddy, Opinion, Forecasting, Prediction Markets and the
Age of Better Information, COINDESK (June 5, 2022, 3:47 PM), https://www.coindesk.com/
layer2/2022/06/04/forecasting-prediction-markets-and-the-age-of-better-information/
[https://perma.cc/LL66-436X].
    73. See Frischmann, supra note 13, at 933-37.
    74. See generally Chason, supra note 6 (comparing blockchain with traditional property
recording).
    75. See GAVIN WOOD, ETHEREUM: A SECURE DECENTRALISED GENERALISED TRANSACTION
LEDGER 7, https://gavwood.com/paper.pdf [https://perma.cc/K65U-JDXB].
    76. See id.
    77. See id. at 17.
    78. See FRISCHMANN, supra note 12, at 24-25.
2023]    BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                              1111

assets, such as copyrights and patents.79 While there are often fees
to record a transaction in these ledgers, equally often they are free
to read—in other words, the information in them is treated as the
public good it is.80
   But while centralized ledgers are straightforward and can be
inexpensive, they have their own serious problems. For one thing,
a centralized administrator has the power to discriminate among
users, undoing the benefits of managing the ledger as a commons.81
While a commons ledger with nondiscrimination rules may be better
for society, the administrator may be better off treating it as a
private resource and raising prices. For another thing, the adminis-
trator could corruptly manipulate the ledger for their own
benefit—by transferring assets to themselves, or by taking bribes to
modify the records in ways that benefit the parties paying them
off.82 Most severely, the administrator could lie about the ledger’s
contents, throwing the integrity of the ledger itself into question.83
   A ledger is centralized when a single party controls the hardware
the ledger operates on.84 This physical control of the embodiment of
the ledger gives them the power to control use of and access to the
ledger as a resource and thus to control the informational contents
of the ledger.85 That is, corruption becomes possible when the
administrator’s private control over the hardware lets them manip-
ulate the common ledger in a way that diverts the private assets
tracked by the ledger to their own benefit.86
   The fear of corruption in centralized ledgers is the impetus for
distributed ledgers, in which numerous maintainers collectively
maintain a ledger. Each maintainer contributes its own private
hardware and effort to maintain a copy of the ledger.87 No single

    79. See Chason, supra note 6, at 163.
    80. See id.
    81. See PRIMAVERA DE FILIPPI & GREG MCMULLEN, COALA & BLOCKCHAIN RSCH. INST.,
GOVERNANCE OF BLOCKCHAIN SYSTEMS: GOVERNANCE OF AND BY DISTRIBUTED INFRASTRUC-
TURE 22 (June 2018), https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-02046787/document [https://perma.
cc/V7K8-5MLM] (explaining the “curator” role).
    82. See id. at 5.
    83. See id.
    84. See id. at 22.
    85. See id.
    86. See generally id. (explaining how curators vetted submissions to the DAO).
    87. See Bronwyn E. Howell, Petrus H. Potgieter & Bert M. Sadowski, Governance of
1112                      WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                     [Vol. 64:1097

participant can exclude a user; no single participant can enter
transactions on their own; no single maintainer can successfully lie
about the ledger’s contents; no single maintainer can corruptly
transfer assets to themselves.88 Dividing the administration among
numerous maintainers can preserve the infrastructural benefits of
commons management while avoiding the dangers of centralized
corruption.

                                 II. SEMICOMMONS

   Decentralization raises its own new challenges. One is the
challenge of creating appropriate incentives. Why should a main-
tainer contribute its resources and effort to supporting the infra-
structure? This is a collective action problem. It would be easier and
cheaper not to participate and instead free ride on the resources and
effort contributed by other maintainers.89 Another pervasive
challenge is governance. In all but the simplest cases, the main-
tainers will have to make contestable decisions about how the
infrastructure should be managed.90 And even in simple cases, they
must still monitor each other to be sure that they are acting in
accordance with their agreed-upon rules.91 Building a sustainable
commons on top of privately contributed resources is a hard
problem.92

A. Definition

  However, it is a problem that has been solved before. In the
Western European medieval open-field system, farmers held
individual private plots of land.93 But livestock were grazed on the


Blockchain and Distributed Ledger Technology Projects 2-3 (May 13, 2019) (unpublished
manuscript), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3365519 [https://perma.cc/
DC95-VERL].
   88. See generally id.
   89. See Henry E. Smith, Governing the Tele-Semicommons, 22 YALE J. ON REGUL. 289, 297
(2005).
   90. See generally Howell et al., supra note 87, at 3, 5-6.
   91. See DE FILIPPI & MCMULLEN, supra note 81, at 19.
   92. Cf. Howell et al., supra note 87, at 11-12.
   93. See Smith, supra note 17, at S459.
2023]   BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                            1113

whole field in common during fallow seasons.94 The farmers literally
reaped the private rewards of their individual strips, but they also
benefitted from the use of the open field for pasturage.95
   Henry Smith generalized the open-field example into a broader
definition of a semicommons.96 In his theory, a resource is a semi-
commons when it satisfies three conditions. The resource must be
held privately with respect to some substantial uses, it must be held
in common with respect to some other substantial uses, and the
private and common uses must substantially affect each other.97
   At first glance, the semicommons form appears to be strictly
worse than a pure commons. Similar to the commons form, the
semicommons form suffers from the challenge of overuse by
commons users.98 This is the classic tragedy of the commons:
peasants will overgraze their sheep on the open field because it is
costless for them to do so.99 And similar to a commons, a semi-
commons suffers from the challenge of underprovisioning by private
users.100 A farmer will be tempted to withdraw their plot from the
common open field, perhaps to devote it to more intensive cultiva-
tion.101 In addition to these commons challenges, the semicommons
also faces the challenge of targeting by commons users who can
choose which private users their use affects.102 A shepherd can pick
whose plot the sheep trample on (bad for the crops) and whose plot
the sheep defecate on (good for the crops).
   The semicommons form is valuable when the gains from partici-
pating in the common use outweighs these costs.103 In the open field,
the semicommons made sense as long as the value of the commons
use (wool and mutton) and the benefits conferred by the commons
use on the private use (manure as fertilizer) exceeded the costs
imposed by the commons use on the private use (trampling of crops)

    94. See id.
    95. See id. at S457.
    96. Henry E. Smith, Semicommon Property Rights and Scattering in the Open Fields, 29
J. LEGAL STUD. 131, 132 (2000).
    97. Id. at 138.
    98. Id.
    99. See id. at 140.
   100. See id.
   101. See id.
   102. Id. at 139.
   103. Id. at 132.
1114                     WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                      [Vol. 64:1097

and the various governance and monitoring costs (keeping an eye on
the shepherd).104 Under those circumstances, each farmer was bet-
ter off participating than not, and the semicommons was stable.105
For a more modern example, the internet semicommons makes
sense as long as the value to a user of online news, video games,
social media, shopping, memes, and the other uses of an internet-
connected computer exceeds the price of a computer and an internet
connection. The resource-management question is whether and how
the distinctive costs of a semicommons—overuse, underprovision,
targeting, governance, and monitoring—can be kept sufficiently
small that they are less than the benefits of the semicommons form.
   Thus, semicommons theory describes a series of characteristic
mechanisms employed as semicommons to modulate resource use
appropriately. One is compensation, to reward private users for
participating in provisioning the common uses.106 Some compensa-
tion is explicit: your monthly bandwidth bill compensates your
internet service provider (ISP) for connecting its network cables to
the rest of the internet.107 Other compensation is implicit: farmers
who participated in the open-field system were rewarded in mutton
from their own sheep and manure of others’ sheep.108 Another is
boundary-setting so that private users can defend themselves
against targeted overuse and abuse.109 In the internet semi-
commons, the Computer Fraud and Abuse Act110 and the trespass
to chattels tort defend the boundaries around individual computers
by protecting owners against attacks that impair the functioning of
their computers.111 A third is scattering so that commons users
cannot target the costs and benefits of their uses to particular


  104. See id.
  105. See id. at 141-42.
  106. See generally Howell et al., supra note 87 (describing miners being rewarded for
participating).
  107. DE FILIPPI & MCMULLEN, supra note 81, at 11-12.
  108. See Smith, supra note 96, at 135-36.
  109. Id. at 162; see also Grimmelmann, supra note 46, at 2827-41 (discussing “defensible
borders” around internet resources).
  110. 18 U.S.C. § 1030.
  111. See, e.g., Josh Goldfoot & Aditya Bamzai, A Trespass Framework for the Crime of
Hacking, 84 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 1477 (2016); Catherine M. Sharkey, Trespass Torts and Self-
Help for an Electronic Age, 44 TULSA L. REV. 677 (2009); Peter A. Winn, The Guilty Eye:
Unauthorized Access, Trespass and Privacy, 62 BUS. LAW. 1395 (2007).
2023]    BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                                 1115

private users.112 In the open-field system, individual plots were held
as long, thin strips.113 This made it impracticable for a shepherd to
park a flock over a specific farmer’s plot, ensuring that both the
trampling and the defecating were spread more evenly over differ-
ent farmers’ land.114 And finally, as in a pure commons, governance
institutions resolve disputes and adjust rules in light of experience
in a way that is broadly acceptable to participants.115
   Not many resources are held as semicommons, but for those that
are, it is an essential analytical framework.116 Robert Heverly and
Lydia Pallas Loren have shown that intellectual property law has
the structure of a semicommons, combining private and common
uses in a mutually overlapping way.117 In other work, Smith has
analyzed water rights as a semicommons, arguing that the literal
fluidity of water as it flows above and beneath different owners’ land
makes the semicommons form appropriate.118 Telecommunications
networks are another good example. Smith has applied semi-
commons theory to analyze equipment sharing under the Telecom-
munications Act of 1996,119 and one of the authors of this Article has


  112. Smith, supra note 96, at 133. Smith treats scattering as a form of boundary-setting,
and in a literal and important sense, it is. However, disaggregating the two roles that
boundary-setting can play is useful. One, which is typified by scattering, makes targeting by
commons more difficult. The other, which is typified by purely private property, makes it
easier for private owners to prevent, detect, and take action against intrusions. Note that
scattering in the open fields made boundary enforcement harder; one point of Smith’s
argument is that scattering’s benefits in preventing targeting outweighed those costs. See id.
at 156-60 (discussing competing theories).
  113. See id. at 146.
  114. See id. at 146-54.
  115. See generally id. (explaining farmers’ governance of a semicommons).
  116. For more on semicommons theory in general, see Lee Anne Fennell, Commons,
Anticommons, Semicommons, in RESEARCH HANDBOOK ON THE ECONOMICS OF PROPERTY LAW
35 (Kenneth Ayotte & Henry E. Smith eds., 2011).
  117. See Robert A. Heverly, The Information Semicommons, 18 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 1127,
1164 (2003); Robert A. Heverly, Revisiting “The Information Semicommons,” 59 IDEA 137,
151 (2018) [hereinafter Heverly, Revisiting the Information Semicommons]; Lydia Pallas
Loren, Building a Reliable Semicommons of Creative Works: Enforcement of Creative
Commons Licenses and Limited Abandonment of Copyright, 14 GEO. MASON L. REV. 271, 295
(2007).
  118. Henry E. Smith, Governing Water: The Semicommons of Fluid Property Rights, 50
ARIZ. L. REV. 445, 475-77 (2008); Henry E. Smith, Semicommons in Fluid Resources, 20 MARQ.
INTELL. PROP. L. REV. 195, 206-08 (2016).
  119. Smith, supra note 89, at 291-93, 300, 302.
1116                       WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                        [Vol. 64:1097

previously argued that the internet as a whole is a semicommons.120
The internet is a particularly apt example because similar to a
blockchain, it is layered: a globally connected common network layer
sits atop a layer of private hardware.121

B. Blockchains as Semicommons

   Seen through this lens, the system of mining rewards for main-
tainers is the necessary glue that holds a blockchain semicommons
together. In Bitcoin, for example, the first miner who successfully
completes a block of transactions and adds it to the chain receives
transaction fees offered by users whose transactions are in that
block.122 By compensating miners, these rewards give them an
incentive to contribute their (private) resources to the blockchain:
specialized hardware, electricity, network connectivity, and mainte-
nance.123 At the same time, transaction fees limit overuse by
(common) ledger users by pricing access.124 Users who pay larger
fees get their transactions processed faster, and the higher the fee,
the less attractive it is to use the blockchain at all.125 Moreover,
transaction fees are broadly nondiscriminatory: they change based
on the intensity of use rather than on the user’s identity or the
value of the use.126
   Mining rewards are also a form of scattering. Under Bitcoin’s
proof-of-work algorithm, a miner’s chances of finding a nonce that

   120. Grimmelmann, supra note 46.
   121. See generally Solum & Chung, supra note 61 (explaining that the internet’s
architecture is layered); ZITTRAIN, supra note 61 (describing the modularity of the internet’s
design).
   122. There are also mining rewards, which allocate previously unallocated Bitcoins to the
miner who successfully mines a block, according to a schedule that will gradually decrease to
zero over time. See Joshua A. Kroll, Ian C. Davey & Edward W. Felten, The Economics of
Bitcoin Mining, or Bitcoin in the Presence of Adversaries, 12TH WORKSHOP ON ECON. INFO.
SEC., 2013, at 5-6. In a sense, because mining rewards dilute the supply of Bitcoin, they
function as a tax paid by all users to miners, in which each user’s contribution is proportional
to their holdings of Bitcoin. We will not further discuss this complication in this Article.
   123. Cf. Howell et al., supra note 87 (describing how incentives and rewards impact
contributions).
   124. See id. at 8-9.
   125. See David Easley, Maureen O’Hara & Soumya Basu, From Mining to Markets: The
Evolution of Bitcoin Transaction Fees, 134 J. FIN. ECON. 91, 92, 97-100 (2019).
   126. See WOOD, supra note 75, at 7 (describing usage-based pricing in the Ethereum
protocol).
2023]    BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                                  1117

makes a block of transactions hash correctly scales with the number
of possible nonces they are able to test.127 This means that, in
expectation, the mining rewards to participants are exactly in
proportion to the computational resources that those participants
contribute to maintaining the blockchain.128 This is statistically
perfect scattering: a miner’s rewards increase with the effort they
contribute, and nothing else.129 In particular, there is no way to
corruptly steer the fees from a transaction to any particular miner—
a user cannot collude with a miner to pocket those fees.130 All
transaction fees go into a common pool, which is then prob-
abilistically scattered out among participating miners.131
   This is exactly the necessary link required between the private
assets on top of the common ledger and the private resources that
maintain it. The link is tight enough to get the incentives against
overuse and for provisioning right: the rewards flow from blockchain
users to blockchain providers, exactly as needed.132 But at the same
time, the two are not so tightly coupled as to vitiate the important
commons features of layers between them.133 Access remains open
to all users on nondiscriminatory terms. Rewarding miners using
on-chain assets holds the whole thing together.
   The other characteristic technical innovation of blockchains—the
convention that the state of the ledger is defined by the longest
chain—is a governance mechanism.134 The convention forces

   127. See generally NARAYANAN ET AL., supra note 11.
   128. See, e.g., id.
   129. See DE FILIPPI & MCMULLEN, supra note 81, at 14.
   130. See E. Napoletano & Benjamin Curry, Proof of Work Explained, FORBES ADVISOR (Apr.
8, 2022, 3:06 PM), https://forbes.com/advisor/investing/cryptocurrency/proof-of-work [https://
perma.cc/8JHQ-NEL2].
   131. The process is a little different in proof-of-stake blockchains. Here, users participate
by temporarily locking up (or “staking”) their cryptocurrency and receive rewards proportional
to the amount they stake rather than to the computational effort they expend. See, e.g.,
Vitalik Buterin, Proof of Stake FAQ, VITALIK (Dec. 31, 2017), https://vitalik.ca/general/
2017/12/31/pos_faq.html [https://perma.cc/E8H9-S6EA] (providing an accessible overview of
proof of stake, its advantages, and its challenges). See generally Phil Daian, Rafael Pass &
Elaine Shi, Snow White: Robustly Reconfigurable Consensus and Applications to Provably
Secure Proof of Stake, 23D INT’L CONF. ON FIN. CRYPTOGRAPHY & DATA SEC. 23 (2019)
(providing an overview of design requirements for proof-of-stake systems). This, too, is a form
of scattering; the strips are on-chain assets rather than off-chain computers.
   132. See Easley et al., supra note 125.
   133. See generally Solum & Chung, supra note 61.
   134. See DE FILIPPI & MCMULLEN, supra note 81, at 14.
1118                    WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                   [Vol. 64:1097

consensus on what the state of the ledger actually is by giving
participants a powerful incentive to agree with each other.135 It is
rational for any given participant to settle on the chain that all the
other participants regard as authoritative, and the convention that
the authoritative chain is the longest one is a game-theoretic focal
point. Observing which candidate chain is longest is easy, and any
situation with multiple competing chains will tend to resolve itself
quickly as one or the other pulls ahead.136
   A participant who dissents about the state of the ledger effectively
forfeits their on-chain assets because no one else will trade with
them.137 That participant also has nothing to gain from mining
work.138 Other participants will not accept the new blocks they
propose.139 Nakamoto consensus is a governance mechanism that
strongly incentivizes agreement.140 The proposal’s rules are norma-
tive: they give participants reason to accept the verdict of the
longest chain.141 That normative force is what holds a blockchain
together.

                               III. GOVERNANCE

   The picture sketched in Part II is striking in its elegance. The key
technical features of a blockchain—cryptographic verification, block
rewards to participants, and longest-chain consensus—fit together
similar to the parts of a finely engineered watch. Driven by their
own private incentives, participants collaborate to produce a com-
mon ledger.142 The protocol itself appears to be the only enforcement
mechanism needed. The blockchain governs itself.
   But that is not the end of the story. It never is. Just as infra-
structural ledgers face challenges that distributed ledgers help
solve, and distributed ledgers face challenges that blockchain

  135. See Howell et al., supra note 87, at 15.
  136. See generally Daian et al., supra note 131.
  137. See Howell et al., supra note 87, at 12.
  138. See DE FILIPPI & MCMULLEN, supra note 81, at 14.
  139. See id.
  140. See generally Bruno Biais, Christophe Bisière, Matthieu Bouvard & Catherine
Casamatta, The Blockchain Folk Theorem, 32 REV. FIN. STUD. 1662 (2019) (discussing the
degree to which the Bitcoin protocol creates incentives against forks).
  141. See id. at 1664.
  142. See id.
2023]    BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                                  1119

semicommons help solve, blockchain semicommons face their own
challenges.
   Blockchain governance looks automated, but it is not.143 The
formal, technical mechanisms embedded in a blockchain protocol are
just one facet of the governance work required to keep a blockchain
functioning as infrastructure.144 Semicommons theory directs our
attention to the ways in which collaboration among blockchain
participants and users can break down and to the governance
institutions that guard against these breakdowns and deal with
their consequences.145 This Part describes six challenges that compel
blockchain participants and users to engage in governance.

A. Protocols and Software

   The first challenge is that blockchains do not spring full-blown
like Athena from the minds of their creators. A blockchain’s
protocol, which describes the format of entries on its ledger, the
messages participants and users exchange with each other, and the
rules for achieving consensus, is a complicated thing.146 The docu-
ment defining the semantics of the Ethereum virtual machine is a
forty-one-page PDF, and that is just a small part of the Ethereum
protocol.147 There are also highly detailed documents defining the
data structures maintained by clients to describe the state of the
ledger, the messages exchanged among clients, and much more.148
Similarly, a blockchain requires software—actual clients that
implement the protocol as runnable code.149 For a complicated

  143. Primavera De Filippi and Greg McMullen have usefully described this distinction as
one between “governance by the infrastructure” (that is, rules embedded in the technical
protocols and enforced by software) and “governance of the infrastructure” (that is, rules that
“operate at the social or institutional level”). DE FILIPPI & MCMULLEN, supra note 81, at 17-
18.
  144. See id. at 16-20.
  145. See id. at 23 (offering the DAO as an example of the limitations of on-chain
governance).
  146. See generally id. (explaining the interaction between blockchain’s hard-coded rules and
governance by individual users).
  147. See WOOD, supra note 75.
  148. See Geth Documentation, GETH, https://geth.ethereum.org/docs/ [https://perma.cc/
5HV9-DM3V] (directory of Ethereum specifications and resources).
  149. See DE FILIPPI & MCMULLEN, supra note 81, at 19 (explaining institutional rules
within technical protocols software enforces).
1120                       WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                        [Vol. 64:1097

blockchain such as Ethereum, this is an immense, complicated piece
of software.150
   There is good news and bad news. The good news is that protocols
and software are information, and as such, they are pure public
goods, so there is no risk of overuse.151 Indeed, blockchain software
is typically open-sourced to induce greater adoption and to attract
greater participation in developing it.152 The bad news is that
protocols and software are information, and as such, they are pure
public goods, so they are at risk of being underprovisioned.153 This
is the classic challenge of information production. Everyone involved
in a blockchain ecosystem benefits from the existence of a rock-solid
protocol and high-quality software, but everyone is also better off
free riding on someone else’s work to develop them.154 In this
respect, blockchain development raises governance challenges
similar to other open-source projects.155
   One typical solution in the blockchain space is to add private
incentives. For example, a new blockchain’s developers will reserve
some on-chain assets for themselves or for the investors who have
funded the development.156 The idea is that once the blockchain is
up and running, those on-chain assets will become valuable, so the
development work can be repaid out of this new store of value.157
One way of doing so, which was particularly faddish a few years ago,


   150. As of June 27, 2022, the Linux version of Geth (the official and most popular
Ethereum client) was a 42.8-megabyte executable. Download Geth—Camaraon (v.1.10.19),
GETH, https://geth.ethereum.org/downloads/ [https://perma.cc/ZXM6-KV5S]. To get a more
visceral sense of Geth’s complexity and scale, go to its official source code repository, Go-
Ethereum, GITHUB, https://github.com/ethereum/go-ethereum/ [https://perma.cc/R27X-QZF7],
and browse through its source code. This is by no means large by the standards of modern
software, but it is hardly trivial, either: this is not something a programmer could dash off in
a couple of weeks.
   151. See Grimmelmann, supra note 46, at 2810.
   152. See Raina S. Haque, Rodrigo Seira Silva-Herzog, Brent A. Plummer & Nelson M.
Rosario, Blockchain Development and Fiduciary Duty, 2 STAN. J. BLOCKCHAIN L. & POL’Y 139,
156 (2019).
   153. See Grimmelmann, supra note 46, at 2811.
   154. See Madison et al., supra note 13, at 666.
   155. Haque et al., supra note 152, at 154-55; Angela Walch, In Code(rs) We Trust: Software
Developers as Fiduciaries in Public Blockchains, in REGULATING BLOCKCHAIN: TECHNO-SOCIAL
AND LEGAL CHALLENGES 58, 58 (Philipp Hacker et al. eds., 2019).
   156. See Haque et al., supra note 152, at 156.
   157. See id.
2023]    BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                                  1121

was the Initial Coin Offering (ICO), in which the developers directly
sell on-chain tokens to the investing public.158
   However, these on-chain asset-based incentives create their own
governance issues. For example, a large stock of reserved tokens
creates the risk that the developers who are hoarding them could
liquidate their positions, flood the market, and undercut the value
of others’ investments. Or the developers could sneak in protocol
changes or software backdoors that primarily benefit themselves.159
For this reason, it is also common to set up a foundation or other
governance institution to steward these assets and to coordinate
development of protocol and software for the benefit of the commu-
nity around the blockchain.160 In this way, blockchains strongly
resemble previous software-governance efforts, such as those re-
sponsible for major open-source projects.161

B. Turtles All the Way Up

  Another complication is that on-chain assets are not always
purely private goods. They can be infrastructure too.162 The most
obvious example is smart contracts. A smart contract is software,
which means someone needs to design, program, and debug it.163
Once a smart contract is created, however, it is an information
good.164 If the source code is shared, then others can reuse it,
creating their own instantiations of the same functionality—or they


   158. Rohr & Wright, supra note 7, at 463-65.
   159. See DE FILIPPI & MCMULLEN, supra note 81, at 21.
   160. See, e.g., Carla L. Reyes, (Un)Corporate Crypto-Governance, 88 FORDHAM L. REV. 1875,
1896 (2020).
   161. Cf. id. at 1895-96 (discussing governance and regulation of blockchain protocol and
software development); see also Haque et al., supra note 152, at 146-47. This connection also
highlights the ways in which blockchain communities inherit the governance challenges of
online communities such as wikis and open-source development efforts because whatever else
it is, a blockchain community is also by necessity a software-development community. See
generally Nicolas Auray, Online Communities and Governance Mechanisms, in GOVERNANCE,
REGULATION AND POWERS ON THE INTERNET 211 (Eric Brosseau et al. eds., 2012) (discussing
online governance challenges); Primavera De Filippi & Benjamin Loveluck, The Invisible
Politics of Bitcoin: Governance Crisis of a Decentralised Infrastructure, 5 INTERNET POL’Y REV.,
Sept. 30, 2016, at 10-15 (analyzing online governance challenges in Bitcoin).
   162. See supra Part I.
   163. See Werbach & Cornell, supra note 2, at 365.
   164. See Heverly, Revisiting the Information Semicommons, supra note 117, at 138-42.
1122                     WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                     [Vol. 64:1097

can modify and extend it to produce derivative smart contracts with
different functionality.
   Thus, the software above a blockchain clearly raises some of the
same resource-governance issues as the software beneath it. Who
pays for the effort invested in design, programming, and debugging?
Should the code be free for reuse by the creators’ competitors? Can
participants in the smart-contract ecosystem trust the creators of
the contract?
   Answers to these and many other questions must be sought, and
solutions come from many of the same mechanisms we have already
seen at a lower level of the blockchain stack. Thus, for example, a
number of smart-contract designs have their own consensus mecha-
nisms that reuse and recombine consensus mechanisms developed
to achieve consensus within a blockchain.165

C. Resource Consumption

   Bitcoin-style proof-of-work consensus mechanisms are inefficient
in a subtle but massive way. As long as the reward for generating
a block times the probability of winning the nonce lottery is greater
than the cost of mining (in hardware, electricity, et cetera), more
miners will enter.166 They will push the probability of winning down
until the net marginal reward from additional mining effort equals
exactly zero.167
   But if users highly value the ledger the blockchain provides, then
they will be willing to spend highly to have their transactions
carried out. Users will push up the transaction fees—and hence the

  165. E.g., JACK PETERSON, JOSEPH KRUG, MICAH ZOLTU, AUSTIN K. WILLIAMS & STEPHANIE
ALEXANDER, GITHUB, AUGUR: A DECENTRALIZED ORACLE AND PREDICTION MARKET PLATFORM
(V2.0) (2022), https://github.com/AugurProject/whitepaper/releases/latest/download/augur-
whitepaper-v2.pdf [https://perma.cc/B3ZY-QWCS]; LORENZ BREIDENBACH, CHRISTIAN CACHIN,
BENEDICT CHAN, ALEX COVENTRY, STEVE ELLIS, ARI JUELS, FARINAZ KOUSHANFAR, ANDREW
MILLER, BRENDAN MAGAURAN, DANIEL MOROZ, SERGEY NAZAROV, ALEXANDRU TOPLICEANU,
FLORIAN TRAMÈR & FAN ZHANG, CHAINLINK, CHAINLINK 2.0: NEXT STEPS IN THE EVOLUTION
OF DECENTRALIZED ORACLE NETWORKS (2021), https://research.chain.link/whitepaper-v2.pdf
[https://perma.cc/H67P-2XP8]; DAO User Guide, DECENTRALAND, https://docs.decentra
land.org/decentraland/dao-userguide/ [https://perma.cc/3NMP-33WZ].
  166. See Gur Huberman, Jacob D. Leshno & Ciamac Moallemi, Monopoly Without a
Monopolist: An Economic Analysis of the Bitcoin Payment System, 88 REV. ECON. STUD. 3011,
3020 (2021).
  167. See id. at 3021-22.
2023]    BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                                  1123

rewards to miners—until the marginal value of having one’s
transaction processed faster exactly equals the additional fee one
must pay to achieve it.168 In equilibrium, therefore, the value the
blockchain collectively delivers for users determines the level of
effort miners collectively expend.169 High prices for on-chain assets
and high transaction fees induce a high level of mining.170
   The result is that the most popular blockchains are immensely,
inefficiently, wastefully overprovisioned. A single entry-level laptop
computer drawing perhaps fifty watts is easily able to store and
maintain a modern blockchain.171 And yet Bitcoin mining consumes
122 terawatt hours per year of electricity, about 0.5 percent of the
world’s entire electricity production, which is as much as Sweden or
Norway.172 The environmental consequences are catastrophic.173
   Unfortunately, some redundancy is essential to trustworthiness.
A centralized database is far more resource efficient, but it sacrifices
the benefits of distributing ledger control among many part-
icipants.174 Thus, a great deal of effort has been put into developing
alternative “proof-of-stake” mechanisms, in which mining rewards
are distributed to participants in proportion to how many on-chain
assets they have at “stake” in the system.175 Ethereum has been
gearing up for a transition from proof-of-work to proof-of-stake for
years,176 and made the leap during the editing of this Article.177
   This, too, is a governance problem. The previous Sections dis-
cussed the problem of developing protocols, but the process of

  168. See Easley et al., supra note 125, at 106.
  169. See id.
  170. See id. at 99, 106.
  171. See Alisa DiCaprio & Maya Marie, Just How Energy Efficient Is Your Blockchain?, R3
(Oct. 21, 2021), https://www.r3.com/blog/just-how-energy-efficient-is-your-blockchain/ [https://
perma.cc/L8WJ-EDQQ].
  172. See Cambridge Bitcoin Electricity Consumption Index, UNIV. OF CAMBRIDGE, https://
ccaf.io/cbeci/index/comparisons [https://perma.cc/5J98-CDWS].
  173. See Michaela Stones, The Environmental Consequences of Cryptocurrency Mining, N.Y.
LEAGUE OF CONSERVATION VOTERS (Nov. 4, 2021), https://nylcv.org/news/the-environmental-
consequences-of-cryptocurrency-mining/ [https://perma.cc/T88L-6H5B].
  174. See, e.g., Buterin, supra note 131.
  175. See id.
  176. See Upgrading Ethereum to Radical New Heights, ETHEREUM, https://ethereum.org/
en/upgrades/ [https://perma.cc/M9EN-KN6M].
  177. See David Yaffe-Bellany, Crypto’s Long-Awaited ‘Merge’ Reaches the Finish Line, N.Y.
TIMES (Sept. 15, 2022), https://www.nytimes.com/2022/09/15/technology/ethereum-merge-
crytpo.html [https://perma.cc/4GFJ-53TT].
1124                   WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                 [Vol. 64:1097

debating and deciding which protocols to use is also governance. In
blockchain communities, these debates take place across a riotous
collection of mailing lists, blogs, news sites, and Discord servers.178

D. Tyranny of the Majority

   In a “51% attack,” a majority of the mining power on a proof-of-
work blockchain collusively hijacks the ledger.179 One way to do so
is by ignoring proposed blocks that come from outside their cartel
and accepting only proposed blocks from members.180 If a cartel with
more than half the mining power does so, then more than half the
proposed new blocks will come from the cartel’s efforts, which means
that given long enough, the cartel is overwhelmingly likely to win
the mining race against all possible competitors. Thus, all of the
block rewards accrue to cartel members. The cartel can also
collectively manipulate the contents of the ledger—for example, by
refusing to recognize certain transactions from nonmembers or by
changing the semantics of the protocol in self-favoring ways.181
   Although the core idea of Nakamoto consensus is elegantly
simple, it only holds under restrictive hypotheses. The game theory
of 51-percent attacks gets very complicated, very quickly. For
example, some results show that groups with less than a majority
of mining power can still extract more than their proportional share
in mining rewards.182 Another point is that participants who are
subject to a 51-percent attack can retaliate by withdrawing from the
blockchain entirely, which functions as a threat to reduce the value
of on-chain assets and potentially deter attacks in the first place.183
In practice, the political maneuvering around mining pools and
transaction processing is far more complicated than the simple
picture of a single focal point suggests.



  178. See, e.g., Richard Yan, The Blockchain Debate Podcast, BUZZSPROUT, https://
blockdebate.buzzsprout.com/ [https://perma.cc/6ZNM-T2GR].
  179. See Kroll et al., supra note 122, at 11-12.
  180. See Ittay Eyal & Emin Gün Sirer, Majority Is Not Enough: Bitcoin Mining Is
Vulnerable, 18TH INT’L CONF. ON FIN. CRYPTOGRAPHY & DATA SEC. 436, 441-42 (2014).
  181. See Kroll et al., supra note 122, at 11-12.
  182. Eyal & Sirer, supra note 180, at 447.
  183. See Kroll et al., supra note 122, at 11-12.
2023]    BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                              1125

   From a resource-governance perspective, what happens in a 51-
percent attack is that the proof-of-work protocol’s antitargeting
properties break down. A cartel with more than half the mining
power can prevent mining rewards from being scattered onto non-
members.184 Therefore, the cartel’s members are able to connect
private on-chain assets to their own private hardware in a way that
disproportionately benefits themselves.
   Another example of clever targeting involves “miner extractable
value” (MEV), in which a clever miner can modify the contents of
the ledger in a way that remains acceptable to other participants
under the longest-chain convention but diverts some resources to
themselves.185 One type of MEV attack involves front-running
proposed transactions so that the miner can capture for themselves
value that a user intended to.186 Another, called a “time-bandit
attack,” involves rolling back transactions already recorded in the
blockchain to capture MEV from previous blocks.187
   These are governance problems that no protocol can fully resolve.
51-percent attacks are inherent to the design of the Bitcoin proof-
of-work consensus mechanism.188 Different consensus mechanisms
create their own opportunities for strategic behavior. For example,
proof-of-stake mechanisms can display rich-get-richer phenomena,
in which whales with large holdings are best able to and most incen-
tivized to stake their holdings for additional rewards.189 Blockchain-
mechanism design is an area of immense practical and theoretical
interest, but there is no silver-bullet protocol design that is fully
incentive-compatible under all circumstances. The governance of a
blockchain semicommons cannot be fully embedded in its protocol.


  184. See id.
  185. See Philip Daian, Steven Goldfeder, Tyler Kell, Yunqi Li, Xueyuan Zhao, Iddo Bentov,
Lorenz Breidenbach & Ari Juels, Flash Boys 2.0: Frontrunning in Decentralized Exchanges,
Miner Extractable Value, and Consensus Instability, 2020 IEEE SYMP. ON SEC. & PRIV. 910,
911.
  186. See id. at 912.
  187. See id. at 921.
  188. See Kroll et al., supra note 122, at 11-12.
  189. See, e.g., Giulia Fanti, Leonid Kogan, Sewoong Oh, Kathleen Ruan, Pramod
Viswanath & Gerui Wang, Compounding of Wealth in Proof-of-Stake Cryptocurrencies, 23D
INT’L CONF. ON FIN. CRYPTOGRAPHY & DATA SEC. 42, 42-43 (2019); Yuming Huang, Jing Tang,
Qianhao Cong, Andrew Lim & Jianliang Xu, Do the Rich Get Richer? Fairness Analysis for
Blockchain Incentives, ACM SIGMOD INT’L CONF. ON MGMT. DATA 790 (2021).
1126                      WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                       [Vol. 64:1097

E. Consensus Breakdown

  A more fundamental governance issue is that blockchain protocols
are not natural laws of the universe.190 Protocols are creatures of
consensus, and they last only as long as that consensus endures.191
A nation’s people can always scrap their constitution and write a
new one, regardless of what the old one said. Similarly, a blockchain
community can always collectively decide to modify its protocol. The
old protocol does not have the power to stop them.192
  Thus, the longest-chain convention, the semantics of a virtual
machine, and other details of a protocol are not inviolate. Some-
times the community collectively decides to change; sometimes an
influential participant steps in and persuades others to go along.193
After the infamous “DAO Hack,” for example, the Ethereum
blockchain adopted a new one-off modification that unwound a
particularly large transaction that many felt had been misappro-
priated.194 Vitalik Buterin, the creator and visionary of Ethereum,
presented this change as a necessary compromise to ensure the
blockchain’s long-term stability and acceptance.195

  190. Another way of making this point is that the technical “decentralization” of a
blockchain as a distributed system with a consensus protocol does not necessarily mean that
a blockchain is decentralized in the sense of not having concentrations of power. See Angela
Walch, Deconstructing “Decentralization”: Exploring the Core Claim of Crypto Systems, in
CRYPTOASSETS: LEGAL, REGULATORY, AND MONETARY PERSPECTIVES 39, 40-41 (Chris Brummer
ed., 2019).
  191. See Grimmelmann, supra note 10, at 17.
  192. See Karen Yeung & David Galindo, Why Do Public Blockchains Need Formal and
Effective Internal Governance Mechanisms?, 10 EUR. J. RISK REGUL. 359, 374-75 (2019)
(arguing that off-chain consensus is necessary to serve as a Hartian rule of recognition
making the state of a blockchain authoritative); cf. Wessel Reijers, Iris Wuisman, Morshed
Mannan, Primavera De Filippi, Christopher Wray, Vienna Rae-Looi, Angela Cubillos Vélez
& Liav Orgad, Now the Code Runs Itself: On-Chain and Off-Chain Governance of Blockchain
Technologies, 40 TOPOI 821 (2021) (describing on-chain governance as a Kelsenian positivist
legal order and subjecting it to the Schmittian critique of the state of exception).
  193. See, e.g., Haque et al., supra note 152, at 156-66 (describing social process by which
protocol changes are proposed, agreed to, and made); Sarah Azouvi, Mary Maller & Sarah
Meiklejohn, Egalitarian Society or Benevolent Dictatorship: The State of Cryptocurrency
Governance, 2018 FIN. CRYPTOGRAPHY & DATA SEC. 127 (analyzing distribution of
contributions to code and discussions).
  194. See Grimmelmann, supra note 10, at 17-19.
  195. See Vitalik Buterin, Onward from the Hard Fork, ETHEREUM FOUND. BLOG (July 26,
2016), https://blog.ethereum.org/2016/07/26/onward-from-the-hard-fork [https://perma.cc/AY
C4-GQMU].
2023]   BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                             1127

   The debates over whether to make these changes are inherently
political.196 Unwinding the DAO Hack required taking a large
quantity of Ether from one user’s address and returning it to other
users’ addresses.197 Not unwinding the hack was equivalent to
saying that the user who found and exploited a bug in a smart
contract’s design was entitled to keep all of the Ether they drained
from an investment club’s joint account.198
   These, too, are governance disputes. The work required to achieve
blockchain consensus becomes most visible in the cases where it
breaks down, where people genuinely argue over what the
blockchain ledger ought to say. In the DAO Hack case, the dispute
was serious enough that the Ethereum blockchain forked into two
mutually incompatible communities.199 One of the communities
unwound the hack in its version of the ledger; the other did not.200

F. Inherent Instability

   A pervasive source of instability in blockchain resource systems
is that they are built using software. No large software project is
ever completely finished or free of bugs. In particular, blockchains
have seen so many bugs and exploits that entire websites are
dedicated to tracking them.201 The need to modify and upgrade
blockchain protocols and software to bring them into line with the
intended design never goes away, and neither does the need to re-
consider the design itself in light of bitter experience. Therefore,
every blockchain is always and forever in motion; it evolves over
time as part of the normal lifecycle of software. This evolution
requires governance work, even if it takes place stably and
invisibly—especially to make it take place stably and invisibly.

  196. See Barton E. Lee, Daniel J. Moroz & David C. Parkes, An Analysis of Blockchain
Governance via Political Economics (Sept. 8, 2021) (unpublished manuscript), https://www.
dropbox.com/s/adfvbeslt20hqpq/Lee_Moroz_Parkes-2019.pdf [https://perma.cc/2FTA-LNUW]
(analyzing blockchain forks using tools from economics and political science).
  197. See Grimmelmann, supra note 10, at 18.
  198. See id.
  199. See id.
  200. See id.
  201. See, e.g., Molly White, WEB3 IS GOING JUST GREAT, https://web3isgoinggreat.com
[https://perma.cc/TV6B-RFZA]; Documented Timeline of Exchange Hacks, CRYPTOSEC, https://
cryptosec.info/exchange-hacks/ [https://perma.cc/Z2S4-CA4U] (last updated Jan. 9, 2022).
1128                     WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                     [Vol. 64:1097

   Similarly, using on-chain assets as incentives creates complex
and poorly understood reward systems that depend on emergent
social behavior. For example, the Terra algorithmic stablecoin
depended on user perception that the on-chain assets being
exchanged for each other would retain enough value that Terra’s
governance foundation could always successfully defend its peg.202
After the stablecoin briefly broke a buck, the confidence deflated
like a popped balloon.203 It hovered very slightly under a dollar for
several days before collapsing completely.204 The crowd dynamics
that at first maintained, and then destroyed, the Terra peg cannot
be captured in its protocol, and yet they are essential to understand-
ing Terra as a resource system. The massive price volatility of
Bitcoin and other cryptocurrencies similarly means that these
resource systems are coupled to the broader economy in ways that
can both promote and undermine their governance mechanisms.205
   Even functioning semicommons are vulnerable to changes in
prices or production technology. Landlords ultimately enclosed the
open-field semicommons.206 In a blockchain, the temptation is al-
ways to add more epicycles to the protocol: new staking mecha-
nisms, new abuse mitigations, et cetera. But no protocol can solve
all governance problems. Constant technological and social change
mean that the incentives, threats, and design alternatives for block-
chains are always shifting. The design parameters that make sense
for a low-transaction-volume store of value for people distrustful of
governmental authority are completely inappropriate for a system
for low-risk, high-volume international remittances, and neither of
them is well suited to a general-purpose distributed computer in-
tended to provide a platform for worldwide collaboration.207 The
shifting mix of private and public values means that no blockchain



  202. See Matt Levine, Opinion, Terra Flops, BLOOMBERG (May 11, 2022, 1:44 PM), https://
www.bloomberg.com/opinion/articles/2022-05-11/terra-flops [https://perma.cc/S3C5-LXSP].
  203. See id.
  204. See id.
  205. See Nicole Lapin, Explaining Crypto’s Volatility, FORBES (Dec. 23, 2021, 6:00 AM),
https://www.forbes.com/sites/nicolelapin/2021/12/23/explaining-cryptos-volatility/
?sh=5f885a997b54 [https://perma.cc/W7WB-HEDK].
  206. See Smith, supra note 96, at 160-61.
  207. See BUTERIN, supra note 25, at 13 (defining goals for Ethereum).
2023]    BLOCKCHAINS AS INFRASTRUCTURE AND SEMICOMMONS                                 1129

resource system instantiates the right governance institution for all
places and all times.

                                      CONCLUSION

   Blockchains are not just scams, hype, and carbon emissions.
There is something novel, nonobvious, and possibly useful here.
Blockchains are a clever new way of providing ledger infrastructure.
Their decentralization avoids some familiar corruption problems.
And semicommons mechanisms address some familiar incentive
problems of decentralization. But as we have shown, blockchains
face governance and incentive challenges of their own—challenges
that can be appreciated and confronted by thinking about block-
chains as infrastructural resource systems.
   Our description of blockchain governance helps make sense of a
paradox in blockchain rhetoric. On the one hand, blockchain
advocates proudly point to the “trustless” nature of blockchains:
participants supposedly can rely on technical features of blockchains
to protect them, rather than on social relations.208 On the other
hand, blockchain advocates also proudly point to the importance of
blockchain communities; they celebrate the social relations par-
ticipants forge by joining with each other to promote the blockchain
vision.209 Which is it, skeptics ask? Are blockchains about individu-
als who are perfectly independent of one another, or are they about
communities richly bound together by social ties? Why does a
trustless world need blockchain communities?

   208. See, e.g., SATOSHI NAKAMOTO, BITCOIN, BITCOIN: A PEER-TO-PEER ELECTRONIC CASH
SYSTEM 1, https://bitcoin.org/bitcoin.pdf [https://perma.cc/344A-D9DU] (“What is needed is an
electronic payment system based on cryptographic proof instead of trust.”); Nick Szabo,
Trusted Third Parties Are Security Holes, NAKAMOTO INST. (2005), https://nakamotoinstitute.
org/trusted-third-parties/ [https://perma.cc/S3SY-DCG3]. For sophisticated analyses of what
“trust” means in this context, see Rebecca M. Bratspies, Cryptocurrency and the Myth of the
Trustless Transaction, 25 MICH. TECH. L. REV. 1 (2018); WERBACH, supra note 8; Bill Maurer,
Taylor C. Nelms & Lana Swartz, “When Perhaps the Real Problem Is Money Itself!”: The
Practical Materiality of Bitcoin, 23 SOC. SEMIOTICS 261 (2013).
   209. See, e.g., Mia Sato, A Trip to the GaryVee Convention, Where Everyone Is Part of Cryp-
to’s 1 Percent, THE VERGE (June 10, 2022, 9:00 AM), https://www.theverge.com/23160201/
gary-vaynerchuk-veecon-veefriends-nfts-web3-conference-crypto [https://perma.cc/FEY4-D2
UV]; Kevin Roose, Crypto Is Cool. Now Get on the Yacht, N.Y. TIMES (Nov. 5, 2021), https://
www.nytimes.com/2021/11/05/technology/nft-nyc-metaverse.html [https://perma.cc/ KCR2-
QMWS].
1130                     WILLIAM & MARY LAW REVIEW                     [Vol. 64:1097

  The paradox dissolves when one realizes that purely technical
descriptions of how blockchains “work” cannot be taken at face
value. Blockchains are technosocial systems, not just technologies.
On-chain stability is possible only because participants engage in
extensive off-chain governance work. The crowds of blockchain
believers encouraging each other to HODL on Discord, or milling
along listlessly while LCD Soundsystem plays at the NFT.NYC
conference, are central to blockchains, not peripheral to them.210
What participants do off-chain matters just as much as what they
do on-chain.
  Scholars and developers must pay close attention to actual
blockchain governance mechanisms, not just the ones formally
instantiated in protocols and code. Collective community governance
decisions are routine, not exceptions. They are a feature, not a bug.
And they make blockchains work.




  210. See Primavera De Filippi, Morshed Mannan & Wessel Reijers, Blockchain as a
Confidence Machine: The Problem of Trust & Challenges of Governance, 62 TECH. SOC’Y, Aug.
2020, at 7-8.