DOKK Library

What is unilateralism in international taxation?

Authors Wei Cui

License CC-BY-4.0

Plaintext
                      doi:10.1017/aju.2020.52




                      SYMPOSIUM ON RUTH MASON, “THE TRANSFORMATION OF INTERNATIONAL TAX”

                                              WHAT IS UNILATERALISM IN INTERNATIONAL TAXATION?

                                                                                            Wei Cui*

                         The Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development (OECD) recently emerged as the site of
                      unprecedented, multilateral, and seemingly high-stakes negotiations about the future of international business
                      income taxation. Judging by the political resources deployed in these negotiations, international tax has entered
                      unchartered territory. Ruth Mason offers a timely and balanced portrayal of the OECD process so far.1 But expla-
                      nations of this process remain eminently contestable. On the one hand, international institutions that address
                      externalities from uncoordinated actions and produce mutual benefits for participating nations can be highly sta-
                      ble. On the other hand, the OECD has struggled, whether in its Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS) and post-
                      BEPS initiatives or during the pre-BEPS era, to articulate the goals for which international coordination in taxation
                      is needed. By many accounts, recent discussions at the OECD are motivated mainly by the desire to stop foreign
                      imposition of taxes on U.S. companies, or, as the other side of the same coin, to avert the wrath of the single
                      hegemonic power in international tax. What is the best characterization of this conflict? I believe that understand-
                      ing the underlying subject matter for international coordination, as opposed to merely the institutions that might
                      facilitate such coordination, is required for identifying the coming transformation of international tax.

                      Without the Consent of the United States

                        Since 2017, the United States has in short succession withdrawn from the Paris Agreement on Climate Change,
                      the Trans-Pacific Partnership, the Iran Nuclear Agreement, and myriad other multilateral agreements. The World
                      Health Organization is only the latest international organization that the Trump administration has spurned,
                      suffering a similar fate to other United Nations bodies, the World Trade Organization, the International
                      Criminal Court, and NATO.2 We seem to live in an age of unilateralism, with the world’s most powerful country
                      becoming the least reluctant to destroy expectations for international cooperation.
                        Yet in the world of international taxation, “unilateralism” has taken on the opposite meaning from what one
                      might gather from general discourses. The term seems essentially to refer to actions taken “without the consent of
                      the United States.” In March 2018, the European Council had proposed two directives for reforming international
                      taxation—a longer-term proposal for allocating taxing rights according to a new notion of “significant economic
                      presence,” which would require EU member states to renegotiate bilateral tax treaties, and a shorter-term proposal




                         * Professor of Law, University of British Columbia, Peter A. Allard School of Law.
                         1
                           Ruth Mason, The Transformation of International Tax, 114 AJIL 353 (2020).
                         2
                           Alex Pascal, Against Washington’s “Great Power” Obsession, ATLANTIC (Sept. 23, 2019).

                                  © Wei Cui 2020. This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://   260
                                  creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided
                                                                                 the original work is properly cited.




https://doi.org/10.1017/aju.2020.52 Published online by Cambridge University Press
                      2020                                       WHAT IS UNILATERALISM IN INTERNATIONAL TAXATION?                                            261

                      for an EU-wide Digital Services Tax (DST) that would be consistent with existing tax treaties.3 The proposed
                      directives failed to attract consensus, in substantial part because some member states feared that they would antag-
                      onize the United States: the digital platforms that would initially be subject to the DST comprised mostly of
                      American companies. France, Spain, Italy, Austria, and the United Kingdom then moved towards enacting
                      DSTs under their domestic laws, either using the 2018 European DST template or adopting similar designs.4
                      Yet these DST proposals quickly came to be known as the unilateral measures. They were widely demonized as
                      threatening some longstanding status quo of international cooperation. Reading commentaries on international
                      taxation in 2019, it was hard to avoid the impression that unilateralism was the most alarming development in the
                      field—except that in this case the United States and its multinationals were the victims, and other countries the
                      perpetrators.
                         This topsy-turvy world forms the subject of Mason’s article. A first contribution of the article is to provide a
                      compelling characterization of the international order, insofar as taxing business income is concerned, that pre-
                      existed the OECD’s BEPS initiative. Mason reminds us that at least among American tax lawyers, “international
                      tax” has often been taken to be a misnomer: “each state makes its tax law independently of other states . . . inter-
                      national tax has consisted of a collection of isolated national tax regimes, connected on a piecemeal basis by bilat-
                      eral tax treaties.”5 Until just seven or eight years ago, the content of “truly” international tax consisted mostly of a
                      Model Tax Convention maintained by the OECD. That Model Convention sports notions such as permanent
                      establishment, arm’s length transfer pricing, and avoiding double taxation—concepts and norms the significance
                      of which may escape even the most attentive non-specialists. Mason also hints at, but does not dwell on, another
                      important fact. The United States, through its domestic legislation, is the source of a long list of important prin-
                      ciples and rules governing income taxation of cross-border transactions. That list includes, among others, the ideas
                      of a foreign tax credit, controlled foreign corporations, limitations on earning stripping and conduit financing, a
                      branch profit tax and dividend equivalent payments, and denying treaty benefits to “hybrid” entities.6 The United
                      States introduced these rules regardless of whether other countries were ready to embrace them. Even in its bilat-
                      eral tax treaties, the United States succeeded systematically to incorporate rules that it would asymmetrically apply
                      to itself, such as limitations of treaty benefits.
                         Essentially, since the 1950s, the United States has been a hegemonic power in international income taxation.
                      Unilateralism is second nature to the country. Not infrequently, other countries borrowed American “international
                      tax” rules and enacted them in their own domestic laws. (It would perhaps be appropriate to put such imitative
                      enactments under Mason’s label, “coordinated unilateralism.”) But at other times, the outcome was more discord-
                      ant. In the years before the launch of the BEPS project, the most important and controversial development in
                      international taxation was the U.S. decision to coerce foreign financial institutions into sharing information on
                      foreign accounts held by American citizens.7 And as recently as 2017, the United States enacted a Base
                      Erosion and Anti-Abuse Tax (BEAT), which imposed a tariff equivalent on what it regarded as excessive pay-
                      ments from the United States to foreign related parties. Both the policy coherence and treaty compatibility of

                         3
                            Proposal for a Council Directive Laying Down Rules Relating to the Corporate Taxation of a Significant Digital Presence, COM (2018)
                      147 final (Mar. 21, 2018); Proposal for a Council Directive on the Common System of a Digital Services Tax on Revenues Resulting from the
                      Provision of Certain Digital Services, COM (2018) 148 final (Mar. 21, 2018).
                         4
                            For a review, see Wei Cui, The Digital Services Tax on the Verge of Implementation, 67(4) CANADIAN TAX J. 1135–1152 (2019). For new UK
                      legislation, see Finance Bill 2019-21 (2020), Parliament: House of Commons. Bill no. 114., Part 2, § 38–71.
                         5
                            Mason, supra note 1, at 353–54.
                         6
                            See Reuven Avi-Yonah, Constructive Unilateralism: U.S. Leadership and International Taxation, 42(2) INT’L TAX J. 17 (2016).
                         7
                            Itai Grinberg, The Battle Over Taxing Offshore Accounts, 60 UCLA L. REV. 304–383 (2012); Ruth Mason, Citizenship Taxation,
                      S. CAL. L. REV. 89, 169 (2016).




https://doi.org/10.1017/aju.2020.52 Published online by Cambridge University Press
                      262                                                            AJIL UNBOUND                                                   Vol. 114

                      BEAT are controversial.8 What is not controversial is that the BEAT not only was unilateral but also defied pre-
                      existing international tax norms.9
                         In short, the international tax status quo that, by Mason’s arguments, has recently been transformed was one in
                      which developed countries’ norms, and especially the hegemonic norms of the United States, shaped national
                      expectations, but in which little explicit multilateral coordination could be found. Bilateral tax treaties constrained
                      some actions of contracting states, but left ample room for others. This raises the question: Why has the interna-
                      tional tax world become so sensitive to unilateralism since 2018?

                      What is Multilateralism for?

                         Mason’s analysis of the BEPS initiative is inextricably tied to this issue. She argues that the BEPS process ush-
                      ered in “major changes in the participants, agenda, institutions, norms, and legal instruments of international tax,”
                      while acknowledging the many critiques that have been made of the BEPS project. In a second important con-
                      tribution, she also offers a neutral, even agnostic, discussion of whether the OECD can succeed to broker a global
                      agreement regarding how to tax the digital economy. Mason’s claim is that as a positive matter, a new set of insti-
                      tutions exist now that did not exist before. This raises the possibility that while “unilateral measures” like the
                      European DST legislation are nothing new by reference to the pre-BEPS status quo, they represent defections
                      from coordination under the post-BEPS regime. Whether multilateralism is the appropriate post-BEPS bench-
                      mark is thus the critical issue, both for evaluating Mason’s claim that international tax is transformed, and for
                      determining the significance of unilateralism today.
                         On this issue, Mason adopts a positive, as opposed to normative, narrative approach. For instance, in discussing
                      the principles sponsored by the OECD, she reports a change from a pre-BEPS dogma of “no double taxation” to a
                      post-BEPS slogan of “full taxation,” without endorsing the soundness of either principle. The truth is that tax
                      specialists have difficulty explaining even to themselves why these ideas are significant, or why multilateral coor-
                      dination is needed to achieve them. Take the bogeyman of “double taxation”. It is obvious that double taxation
                      might have been a challenge when two countries could each tax the same corporate income at a 50 percent or
                      higher rate—the 1950s scenario. It is less obvious what the problem is when the same income is taxed at 12 percent
                      (or lower) in Ireland and again at 21 percent (or lower) in the United States—the scenario today. In fact, most
                      countries adopt measures under their own domestic laws either to exempt foreign-source income from taxation,
                      or to allow credits or deductions for foreign taxes paid. Consequently, double taxation, even when it might be a
                      problem, is substantially alleviated by unilateral solutions.
                         As to the new norm of “full taxation”, Mason aptly points out that we do not yet know what it means: does it
                      mean taxation at 12 percent, 21 percent, or some higher or lower rate? Further, if “full taxation” conveys the goal
                      to stop the abusive use of tax havens to generate “stateless income,”10 it has been persuasively argued that uni-
                      lateral means often suffice to implement such a goal.11 In fact, a careful reader can infer from Mason’s review of the


                         8
                           Chris William Sanchirico, Earnings Stripping Under the BEAT, TAX L. REV. (forthcoming); H. David Rosenbloom & Fadi Shaheen,
                      The BEAT and the Treaties, 92 TAX NOTES INT’L 53 (2018).
                         9
                           Pascal Saint-Amans, director of the OECD’s Centre for Tax Policy and Administration, was quoted as saying that the United States,
                      through enacting the BEAT, “passed a vote of no confidence” in the arm’s length principle. Josh White, OECD Looks Beyond the Arm’s-Length
                      Principle, INT’L TAX REV. (Feb. 01, 2019).
                         10
                            Edward D. Kleinbard, The Lessons of Stateless Income, 65 TAX L. REV. 99 (2011).
                         11
                            Dhammika Dharmapala, Do Multinational Firms Use Tax Havens to the Detriment of Other Countries? (CESifo Working Paper No. 8275,
                      2020).




https://doi.org/10.1017/aju.2020.52 Published online by Cambridge University Press
                      2020                                       WHAT IS UNILATERALISM IN INTERNATIONAL TAXATION?                                                     263

                      substantive elements of BEPS that most of the BEPS measures could be, and have been, adopted by individual
                      countries themselves.
                          In other words, it is not easy to rationalize the OECD tax forum as an indispensable international institution:
                      What are the externalities of unilateral actions that must be addressed, and that countries are willing to address,
                      through cooperation?12 For the reasons just given, the invocation of either double taxation or double non-taxation
                      does not answer this question. While it has long been thought that tax competition creates negative externalities,
                      solutions to this problem have been elusive both in theory13 and in practice.14 The OECD certainly has not tackled
                      tax competition in recent years. The implementation of BEPS recommendations may even intensify tax compe-
                      tition.15 If countries cannot agree on principles that genuinely require cooperation to implement, but can agree
                      only on principles that do not require cooperation, it would be surprising for a transformative multilateral order to
                      emerge.
                          Without knowing the benefits of cooperation under the post-BEPS OECD framework, the assertion that inter-
                      national taxation has been transformed becomes a purely positive claim that requires testing against alternative
                      narratives. Although Mason acknowledges critiques of specific BEPS recommendations, she gives less attention to
                      alternative characterizations of the BEPS process.16 Certain tensions in her narrative also generate skepticism. For
                      instance, if, as by her account, institutionalized coordination pre-BEPS was minimal, one would not expect the
                      OECD to be the site of deep tax policy prowess. While the OECD specialized in elaborating the language of tax
                      treaties, this is not equivalent to “making extensive recommendations for changes to domestic law.”17 In that case,
                      the claim that the OECD has a legitimate role because of its “deep technical expertise”18 sounds revisionist.
                      Another example is the degree to which the BEPS initiative is legitimated by the Inclusive Framework. Mason
                      presents the Inclusive Framework as a major element of international tax’s transformation. Yet in a treatment
                      of the very same BEPS initiative published in 2016,19 the Framework was not even mentioned. This is because
                      the Framework was only established in 2016, after the BEPS Action Plan was announced by the OECD and G20 in
                      October 2015.20
                          It is important to note these narrative tensions; when the gains from feasible cooperation are meagre, we should
                      be aware that the push for “multilateralism” could come from interest groups in particular countries. The history
                      of trade agreements offers ample illustrations of such possibility.21 The current effort led by the OECD to address


                         12
                            See generally, Alan Sykes, International Law, in 1 HANDBOOK OF LAW AND ECONOMICS (A. Mitchell Polinsky & Steven Shavell eds., 2007).
                         13
                            Michael Keen & Kai Konrad, The Theory of International Tax Competition and Coordination, 5 HANDBOOK OF PUBLIC ECONOMICS ch. 5 (Alan
                      Auerbach et al. eds., 2013).
                         14
                            See Lilian V. Faulhaber, The Trouble with Tax Competition: From Practice to Theory, 71 TAX L. REV. 311 (2018).
                         15
                            Richard Collier & Giorgia Maffini, The UK International Tax Agenda for Business and the Impact of the OECD BEPS Project (Oxford
                      University Centre for Business Taxation Working Paper 15/13, 2015).
                         16
                            See, e.g., Sissie Fung, The Questionable Legitimacy of the OECD/G20 BEPS Project, 10 ERASMUS L. REV. 76 (2017), which suggests that the
                      OECD secretariat opportunistically interpreted G20 pronouncements as a political mandate to advance its work on BEPS, and began feed-
                      ing the G20 with action plans, reports, progress updates, and other contributions of its own initiative.
                         17
                            Mason, supra note 1, at 369.
                         18
                            Id.
                         19
                            Itai Grinberg, The New International Tax Diplomacy, 104 GEO. L.J. 1137–1196 (2016).
                         20
                            One criticism of the Inclusive Framework is thus that it was a framework for all countries in the world to implement an agenda set by
                      the traditional OECD countries.
                         21
                            See, e.g., Keith E. Maskus, Economic Development and Intellectual Property Rights: Key Analytical Results from Economics, in 2 THE ECONOMICS OF
                      INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW (Peter Menell & David Schwartz eds., 2016).




https://doi.org/10.1017/aju.2020.52 Published online by Cambridge University Press
                      264                                                            AJIL UNBOUND                                                      Vol. 114

                      tax challenges from digitalization of the economy also raises suspicion. As many commentators have recognized,22
                      this effort has morphed into one that posits only one criterion of success—whether it can shield American com-
                      panies from the proliferation of DSTs.

                      A Transformation Underway

                         Nonetheless, Mason is right that developments in international tax deserve fresh attention from all students of
                      international economic law. For quite different reasons from those she offers, I believe we now stand at the cusp of
                      a genuine transformation of international tax.
                         Three new facts about international trade underlie this upcoming transformation.23 First, digitization has vastly
                      expanded global trade in services. Many digital services are produced and delivered at zero marginal cost, implying
                      that producers must rely on market power to sell such services profitably. This is leading to a situation where many
                      small countries could gainfully impose the equivalent of import tariffs on tradeable services.24 Rather than com-
                      peting to lower tax rates to attract capital, small countries are now likely to raise taxes on service imports used in
                      either consumption or production.
                         Second, digital services can often be delivered simultaneously to multiple countries. This enhances the bargain-
                      ing power of service-importing countries: “doing business elsewhere” becomes a less credible threat.
                         Third, much global digital commerce is asymmetrical for technological reasons. Research and development are
                      driven by agglomeration economies. Large countries can build insurmountable advantages in generating data.
                      This, ironically, renders the technologically powerful countries less capable of threatening retaliation. In response
                      to tariffs on the services they export, they are limited to using tariffs on traditional, non-zero-marginal goods. This
                      predicament arguably characterizes the United States’ situation today: if it is willing to slap an extra 25 percent
                      tariffs on US$1.3 billion worth of French goods just in retaliation for the DST,25 what will it do when the EU
                      counters with tariffs on American services and intellectual property?26
                         New forms of national strategic behavior in the context of global services trade may generate new externalities,
                      which in turn engender new rationales for international cooperation. At present, these externalities are not fully yet
                      understood. But they may well redefine the subject matter of international taxation.




                         22
                            Peter A. Barnes & H. David Rosenbloom, Digital Services Taxes: How Did We Get Into This Mess?, 97 TAX NOTES INT’L 1255 (2020);
                      Robert Goulder, Rethinking the Taboo: Do DSTs Deserve Their Bad Rap?, TAX NOTES INT’L. (May 8, 2020).
                         23
                            For a preliminary discussion, see Cui, supra note 4.
                         24
                            In Robert Staiger & Alan Sykes, The Economic Structure of International Trade-in-Services Agreements (NBER Working Paper No. 22960,
                      2016), Staiger and Sykes argue that the structure of the General Agreement on Trade in Sercives can be explained if tariff-equivalents on
                      services are impossible and physical establishments are required for trades in services. In the international taxation sphere, by contrast,
                      momentum for reform has arisen precisely because much service trade no longer requires physical presence, and tariff-equivalents for
                      services now abound.
                         25
                            Stephanie Soong Johnston, United States to Hit Back at French Digital Tax With New Tariffs in 2021, TAX NOTES INT’L (July 20, 2020).
                         26
                            Jakob Hanke Vela, EU Looks to Target Big Tech in Trade War with America, POLITICO (July 20, 2020).




https://doi.org/10.1017/aju.2020.52 Published online by Cambridge University Press